Concerned by increased valuation of the Chinese currency, rising
Chinese labor and benefits costs, and eastern China's less favorable tax
treatment, companies began looking toward Vietnam for other global sourcing
opportunities. With relatively plentiful young labor and plans to build new
ports near Hanoi and Ho Chi Minh City, the Vietnamese government was working
hard to attract new factories. However, the Vietnamese government was about
20 years behind its Chinese counterparts in export-related infrastructure
investment.
By late 2006, production had migrated en masse to Vietnam and the
production shift continues to this day. One furniture executive predicted
that most of the furniture industry would soon be in Vietnam, but he also
noted that Vietnam needed to upgrade its roads and its only deep-water port
(Thomas, 2008). Furniture is one of the most space-consuming products and the
United States' largest containerized imports by volume (U.S. Census
Bureau, 2009). The value of furniture-classified exports from Vietnam to the
United States increased 1,405 percent between 2002 and 2007 (U.S. Trade
Statistics, 2009). Other industries such as toys and electronics moved into
Vietnam between 2006 and 2008. For example, in 2006, Intel announced greater
investment in Vietnam than in China over the previous decade (Folkmanis,
2006). The exports that moved via ocean put an enormous strain on the port
infrastructure and the inadequate road infrastructure (Conti, 2009).
Inflation spiked from an estimated 7.3 percent to over 25 percent by May 2008
(U.S. Department of State, 2008) as the country was impacted by rapid growth.
Cargo sat on the docks waiting for consolidation, and furniture
containers congested roads to the various ports and the feeder vessels. To
move from the outlying factories to the port, container trucks competed with
motorbikes and cars on city streets. The new ports, scheduled for completion
in 2009 at Hiep Phuoc and Vung Tau, offered little short-term relief. Trucks
moving with the 40-foot "High Cube" containers popular for
furniture and other light goods had to take circuitous routes or hire a
person to push low-hanging telephone wires above the tall container during
transport. Ocean freight companies began to levy new surcharges to
consolidate freight and reduce the allowed dwell time for freight awaiting
consolidation. Local landlords found that they could charge rates higher than
Shanghai, Hong Kong and Los Angeles and receive a two and a half year payback
on their warehouse investment (Anonymous, 2009b). Capacity issues caused
delays in unloading ships that could cost $5,000--$6,000 U.S. per day. Prices
to transport by air versus ship increased costs from around $1,100 U.S. per
container to $32,000 U.S. per container (Tam, 2009). The performance impact
of these unexpected changes was severe.
The theory of FMR provides a broad framework that suggests
organizations be wary of FMR for inputs from adjacent and unrelated
industries. However, it does not provide any specifics regarding when such
risk may exist, only that it may. The above cases of Vietnam and China
offshoring provide initial evidence for the following propositions:
Proposition 1: Moving a significant quantity of offshore production to a new geographic area will create FMR for capacity of supply chain services. (2) Proposition 2: Firms that anticipate and plan for impending FMR for supply chain services from product and nonproduct-market rivals will experience better on time performance of goods produced in that region than those that only focus on the behavior of product-market competitors. Proposition 3: Firms that anticipate and plan for impending FMR for supply chain services from product and nonproduct-market rivals will experience better cost performance on goods produced in that region than those that only focus on the behavior of product-market competitors.
Shifting market conditions create these situations, and impair the
organization's ability to achieve its sustainable competitive advantage.
Although the first proposition may seem obvious, rivalry and its negative
impact are commonplace in global markets; the rivalry for supply chain
services often seems to be unanticipated, creating disruptive effects. When
rivals in the same or different industries are using similar resources,
effectively managing those resources becomes even more critical to a
firm's competitive advantage (Sirmon et al., 2008). Perhaps more
importantly, propositions 2 and 3 suggest that although such shortages may be
inevitable, the ability to effectively cope with them by managing supply
chain assets more effectively than others creates an opportunity to increase
competitiveness.
The potential for logistics and other supply chain capacity
problems should be obvious; however, the movement of manufacturing from China
to Vietnam reveals that they are not. As Markman et al. (2009) point out,
competitive blind spots evolve. Even when there is no product rivalry, mobile
and versatile resources such as many types of unskilled and entry-level labor
and transportation capacity, can cause new and unexpected firms to compete in
factor-markets. Domestic examples presented in the following section further
support that supply chain services are subject to FMR.
---Journal of Supply Chain Management Jan-2013
---Journal of Supply Chain Management Jan-2013
No comments:
Post a Comment